Winery Location
The best way for a winery to
interact with consumers is through a physical winery with a
tasting room. By interacting on a personal level, the
consumer is engaged, has a positive social experience, and
attains a sense of ownership of the winery and the shared
experience. In a study using wineries that also have
urban tasting rooms, it has been shown that such consumers
purchase the wines from that winery to a very significantly
greater extent than they do at the corresponding urban
tasting rooms, despite the proximity of these tasting rooms
to the consumers' domiciles, yielding both greater overall
purchases and greater purchases per consumer. The wine
purchased by a consumer in a tasting room is usually at the
full retail price, or close to it. The Lolonis property is
located far away from the San Francisco Bay Area, but within
range of a day trip. It offers a winery facility in which to
entertain guests and sell wine, on at least an invitational
basis. It is located near other wineries similarly
inclined. From that perspective, it offers the basis
for consumers to develop a relationship with GAN EDEN.
Unlike many areas of the USA,
California has a robust independent grape-growing industry,
and such fruit is easily accessible. As long as one
has a facility available, one can produce wine using
purchased fruit, in order to sell as soon as possible.
Other areas of the United States do not necessarily have
robust independent grape industries capable of furnishing
fruit to independent wineries. In those areas, the
winery must grow its own grapes, the time frame of the first
harvest being at least three years down the line.
Other areas of the USA likewise do not typically have existing vacant bonded
winery facilities accessible by those wishing to produce
wine in quantity. Thus, one would likely need to
purchase land, construct and equip a winery, plant and
cultivate a vineyard, and crush the first grapes at least 3
years afterward. That is, unless one trucked in fruit
from independent growers outside of the region, or purchased
a fully operational winery and vineyard, likely available
only at a considerable premium. Lolonis Winery offers
us the opportunity to enter the industry and develop our
brand and marketing almost immediately, and relatively
inexpensively. Surplus cash flow from sales can be
used to fund development of our own vineyard and winery
facility after the brand has market presence.
It should be noted that because
of lack of a Jewish community and other kosher wineries in
the area, those visiting would largely be nonJewish and
represent the general wine market. Thus, those who
would benefit specifically from the location of the winery
would help establish the brand in the general
marketplace. One would hope to by that time be
producing under our own bond and brand, and have our own signage so that our brand,
not Lolonis Winery, would be the visible trademark.
The best way for a winery to
attract people interested in kosher wine would be to place
the winery in an area easily accessible by the orthodox, and
to a lesser extent, conservative Jewish communities.
The vast majority of Jews in the United States are located
on the eastern seaboard in the New York Metropolitan Area,
with lesser communities located in other mid-Atlantic
communities. A winery anywhere north of northern
Virginia would be in a position to attract Jewish consumers
from the entirety of the eastern Jewish communities. This
would be the optimal place to have a winery. However,
1) The climate favors eastern grape varieties and
French/American hybrids, which do not have a history of
producing premium wine commanding the types of prices we
desire to attain, 2) European grapevines (Vitis Vinifera)
can sometimes be grown, but are subject to fungal
diseases and cold damage, making such vines expensive to
grow, 3) there are few wineries for lease or sale, 4) grapes
meeting our specifications will likely only be available if
we grow them ourselves, which is an expensive and
time-consuming option.
Be that as it may, there is one
existing winery and vineyard estate available in
Pennsylvania, which could be attractive. It
would cost considerably more than producing wine at Lolonis,
but could have the advantage of accessibility to the Jewish
communities of the entire mid-Atlantic and the New York
Metropolitan area, and maybe even the Boston area.
Anyone interested in investing in would be given that
information.
Assumptions Revisited
Wineries have enhanced some
fortunes, laid waste to others. A poorly run winery,
like any other poorly run business, has little hope of
success, but a well-operated winery has as much chance of
success as any other business. Like any business the
greatest chance of success when expenditures are held very
low, and selling prices and growth are maximized.
However, projections must be realistic.
In this case, I believe the
assumptions I made are reasonable. This is an age
where $200 bottles are not uncommon. Under $15 per bottle is
considered downright cheap, and under $20 is considered
almost uniformly to be entry-level. I believe an average
retail price of $25 for a premium wine should be
achievable. In fact, I consider it to be low. It
is not uncommon for wineries to provide several tiers of
wine to consumers. In the old days, it was the
standard premium product and the reserve level
product. These days, there are often multiple reserve
levels. I consider a $25 average retail level to be
reasonable for the standard premium level, in both the
general and kosher marketplaces.
The $25 retail price does not
mean that the gross return to the winery is $25, unless that
wine is being sold entirely on a direct-to-consumer
basis. At this initial proposed production level of
5000 cases, 1000 of which are in each production category of
dry white, dessert white, rose', light red and robust red,
this should be achievable in the first year, using social
media. At future levels, however this may not be
achievable without the addition of a well-located tasting
room. It is far more likely that retailers will play a
role in the sale of these wines. Direct sales to
retailers can be performed in California, and a very few
other markets. Most states require the winery to sell
through an in-state wholesaler. Thus, outside of
California, access to consumers will likely require sales at
a price approximately half of the retail price, while within
California, sales will be split between direct sales to
consumers and direct sales to retailers, and may reasonably
be expected to be around $200 to retails stores, with
overall sales in California averaging around $200 per
case. I'm figuring half will be sold to distributors
out-of-state, 1/4 to retailers in California and 1/4 direct
to consumers nationwide. The initial production of
1000 cases per variety has the capability of being sold
almost entirely direct to consumer. However, it is
worthwhile using it to gain a market presence in stores both
within and outside California. Therefore, for the sake
of projections, I am still considering $200/case will be the
typical selling price. The next vintage, there will be
2000 cases of each category of wine. This can be 2000
cases of the same White or Rose', if the initial one has
proven successful, or could be 1000 cases each of 2
different types, if the initial type is unsuccessful.
Fruit for the next vintage could be purchased on the spot
market close to harvest, to maximize flexibility. Subsequent
vintages, and all vintages of red, there would be
considerable flexibility as well.
As can be seen, there is
considerable benefit derived from higher selling
prices. At the $300/case level, the winery breaks even
in less than 3 years, and even generates about $3 Million
per year after that, even with no further expansion.
Furthermore, it is generating this amount with a bare $2
Million investment. As $25 per bottle is considered a very
reasonable selling price for a premium level of wine, and
due to the proposed rapid increase in production levels, it seems reasonable to
add a "reserve" level of wine as soon as possible, to
generate higher returns, no matter what the actual average
return to the winery turns out to be. It also seems
reasonable to enhance direct sales to consumers as much as
possible.
Projections
At the $150/case level, it
requires an investment of close to $3 Million, and the
winery does not break even until the end of the 8th wine
production year. It is not a great investment, and
afterwards generating about $500K per year over
expenditures. Clearly this is not worth any
investment by a real investor. However, as a "worst
case scenario" (though as I said, there is still the
potential to get worse), it is likely that the original
principal of the investment could be recovered and even a
small profit. At $200/case, this becomes a very
reasonable, though not spectacular, investment. The
winery breaks even before the end of its 5th year, and
generates $1.5M per year thereafter, on a total investment
of about $2.5Million. That is enough to temporarily
spend a sizable chunk for marketing expenses designed to
enhance both the volume and selling price of the wine.
It is here that I point out
that none of my business plans have specifically broken out
"marketing" as a category of expenditures. As I
explained in my page on "business assumptions", I used very
broad categories for expense allocations. The money
for marketing at this initial level of 1000 cases per
category is built into the system. Even at 2000 cases
per category, I feel confident that money can be found in
the system as part of the very vague categories allocated to
expenditures. At 4000 cases per wine type category,
especially if the category is populated by only 1 wine,
there will probably be the need to supplement marketing
expenditures. especially in the third year (when we are
first introducing the 4000 case production level of each
category), and especially at the higher price points.
It is highly worthwhile to attempt to sell the wine at as
high a price as possible. Thus, it may be desirable to
increase the price of some wines, but not others, in order
to maximize the average selling price. It may be
worthwhile to introduce a reserve program of the wines which
we feel will be most saleable in such a program. Here
is a cash flow picture to illustrate the desirability of
maximum selling prices:
10 years of Projected Running Cash Flows at
Various Selling Prices
These are the end-of-year running cash flows projected out 10
years. The operating expenditures are the same at every
price level (not quite true, because after a few years, I
decided not to purchase more equipment at the $150/case level,
because the cash flows did not justify it). After the
winery reached a stable 20,000 case production and a stable
20,000 cases in sales per year, The difference between income
and expenditures projects to $580,008 at $150/case, $1,398,008
at $200/case and $3,398,008 at $300/case. At $200/case
and $300/case, there is easily enough profit for both
distributions and for internal investment, perhaps in a
vineyard and winery estate.
Hidden Money
Discovered!
There is hidden money built
into this business plan, but it must be tapped. The
business plan figures 50 cases per ton. The typical
yield, in reality, is 63 cases per ton. At the initial
100 ton production level, we could have not 5000 cases, but
26% more than that, 6300 cases. I was really looking at a
worst case scenario for yields, which I doubt would occur on
any sort of regular basis across the spectrum of wine being
produced. Ideally, at least 1000 cases of this
"surplus" could be sold at a minimum of $150/case to yield
$150,000 in hidden money, with 300 cases being reserved as
sales samples and wine for investors' and employee
use. A typical pallet of wine is 56 cases, so that is
about 1 pallet per variety. This extra wine would be
available proportionally in each vintage, unless there were
very low yields in a given year. Considering that
California is in a long-term drought, there is always the
possibility that yields of one or more varieties could be
low. The projections took this into account. At
the 20,000 case production level, this is a potential
surplus of 5200 cases, representing close to $1 Million in
sales that can be put towards paying accelerating the
break-even point, distributed to investors, put towards
future investment costs for real estate or other
expansion. It should also be noted that by recovering
juice bottoms and lees, an additional "hidden" wine
amounting to up to 7 percent of normal production could be
available to sell. Money for purchasing additional
equipment remains in the budget for such purposes.
Winery Continuity
It would be inconsistent with
the goal of this proposal, that GAN EDEN be an ongoing,
permanent fixture in the California landscape of premium
wine producers, especially those qualified to be considered
kosher by those desiring that qualification, to allow the
winery to decay when I am no longer able to operate
it. It is my intention to identify someone with the
desire to work by my side, and train that person with the
intention of taking on an ever-increasing role in wine
production, and potentially in other areas of business
operations as well. The winery should be capable of
robust growth in my absence, to the benefit of all
investors, my family, and of course, the employees. I
currently have some names under consideration.
Conclusion
The production of GAN EDEN
wine has the potential of being a good to great investment
opportunity. The least expensive access to a
potentially kosher-dedicated winery is through the lease of
Lolonis Winery. The most time- effective method of
establishing GAN EDEN is through use of the Lolonis Winery
and its permits and licenses.